The Income Effect describes the change in a consumer's demand for a good or service based on the change in their purchasing power, which is itself caused by a change in their real income. In simpler terms, when your money can suddenly buy more or less than it could before, how does that change your shopping habits? Imagine the price of gasoline drops significantly. You still have the same amount of money in your wallet, but your effective wealth has increased because you're spending less to fill up your tank. This boost to your real income means you have extra cash. The income effect examines what you do with that windfall. Do you buy more gasoline and take a road trip? Or do you use the savings to buy something else entirely, like a fancy dinner or another share of your favorite stock? The income effect isn't about getting a pay raise; it's about how price changes for goods you already buy make you feel richer or poorer, and how that feeling influences your spending.
The core idea is that a change in the price of a product directly impacts your purchasing power.
Let's use a simple coffee example. Say you budget $20 per week for lattes, and each latte costs $4, allowing you to buy five. If the coffee shop drops the price to $2.50, you can still get your five lattes for only $12.50. You now have an extra $7.50 of purchasing power each week. The income effect is the decision you make because you have this extra $7.50.
It's almost impossible to discuss the income effect without mentioning its partner in crime, the substitution effect. When a price changes, both effects happen simultaneously and influence your final decision.
In our coffee example, the latte dropping to $2.50 not only makes you feel richer (income effect) but also makes it a much better deal compared to a $3.50 cup of tea (substitution effect). The substitution effect tempts you to substitute away from the more expensive tea and buy more of the now-cheaper lattes. The total change in your coffee-buying habits is a combination of both these powerful forces.
How you react to a change in real income depends heavily on the type of good in question. Economists sort them into two main categories.
These are the goods you'd expect. For normal goods, as your income increases, your demand for them also increases. When a price drop makes you feel wealthier, you'll buy more of these items.
These are a little counterintuitive. For inferior goods, as your income increases, your demand for them decreases. You buy them because they are affordable, and you gladly replace them with better alternatives once you can.
A rare and mostly theoretical third category is Giffen goods, an extreme type of inferior good where a price increase leads to an increase in demand because the income effect is so powerful it overwhelms the substitution effect. These are fascinating for academics but have little practical relevance for most investors.
Understanding the income effect isn't just an academic exercise; it provides a powerful lens for analyzing the economy and individual companies. A savvy value investor can use this concept to make better decisions.